esauboeck
Necessary Social Factors for
Auctions Since the Classic Era
George Boeck
Dissertation, University of Pennsylvania
Department of Folklore and Folklife,1982
This chapter presents an institutional history. The auction will
be traced from its first mention in Babylonia to its present form
as a technique for livestock marketing. Although such a history
has not been previously undertaken, this sketch will not be
comprehensive. Secondary sources provide an outline necessary to
establish the character of the cattle auction market. The
conditions necessary for the presence of auction markets, a money
economy and trade with distant or foreign markets, are part of
this character, as are those factors which led to the auction
market replacing the livestock commission. While both methods are
gesellschaftlich, the auction provides the livestockmen with more
direct participation in marketing as well as a community- based
opportunity for social interaction. As the folklife scholar might
expect, change in large social institutions occurs once people
have a practicable course providing greater opportunity for
Gemeinschaft.
Markets are necessary precursors of auctions. This brief history
establishes the earliest occurrence of auctions, and, more
important, differentiates these forms from modern auctions. In
Agrarian Sociology of Ancient Civilizations, Max Weber sought to
provide a basis for economic discussions of non-capitalistic
societies. Herein, he notes that Mesopotamian trade, while highly
developed, rested upon government price setting (Babylon under
Hammurabi) or market control using royal and temple storehouses
(Weber 1976: 103-4). For instance, cattle taken as booty in
Assyria under Assurbanipal were sold back to the Assyrians at
fixed prices. Under Sargon, grain and sesame from royal
storehouses were sold to keep the prices down in times of
scarcity.
In a similar, perhaps more successful attempt, Polanyi covers some
of the same material from the perspective of the trader (Note 2).
He defines Babylonian trade as a marketless economy. Here, the
traders act as middlemen working on commission. While the tamkarum
(governmental market officers) more or less set prices, they could
also auction the traders' goods upon request (Polanyi 1957: 24).
As exciting as the presence of auctions in Babylon may be, Polanyi
specifidally warns that these auctions and brokerage were devices
for arranging exchange in the absence of money. Once markets
developed, they became superfluous. As currently practiced,
auctions have reappeared "in a sophisticated form and in a new
role of assisting the functioning of highly developed markets"
(Polanyi 1957:15).
In antique Greece, the military expedition continued to be a
significant means of acquiring trade goods. Polayi discusses these
expeditions at some length, mentioning that Spartan "booty
sellers" accompanied the military to auction captured slaves and
cattle (Polyani 1957:85). Terrance K. Hopkins, contributing to the
same volume of essays, states that such auctions ranked among the
precursors of markets (Hopkins 1957: 268). Two related inventions
by the Greeks deserve mention here: the market and coinage. Prior
to the sixth century B.C., people bartered for small articles. F.
M. Heichelheim discusses the prevalence of barter due to problems
of record keeping and transaction size. He points to the
cumbersomeness of money or even a wheat standard in any but
substantial transactions. Recording transactions, sometimes under
penalty of death for failure to do so, generally proved beyond the
capacity of smaller traders (Heichelheim 1958: 130-133).
Coinage as a vehicle of participation liberated the common man.
Quoting Heichelheim: Small silver money enabled fishers and
peasants of Greece for the first time to compete with the larger
owners in selling their products on the market (Heichelheim
1958:252). Necessarily, the development of the market was
synchronous with that of coinage. The nascent Athenian market
moved from near the Acropolis to the Agora in the early sixth
century B.C. (Ancient 1971: 1-4). As foreign trade increased, this
port location became increasingly active. Heichelheim would
conclude that the price variations at the deigma (a samples show
room in the Agora) indicate the capitalistic nature of the classic
economy (1958:62).
Polanyi would disagree with this conclusion. For the purposes of
this study, however, it is enough to say that haggling developed
into auctioneering as buyers bid on samples of inexpensive foreign
goods displayed in a market (Heichelheim 1958:62) (Note 3). At the
outset of the only history of modern auction practices, Wilhelm
Stieda mentions that auctions similar to our own did not exist
until Roman times. Contradicting Heichelheim, Stieda maintains
that auctions in Greece were conducted exclusively by the State
rather than by business interests: Die Griechen kannten die
Auktion nur bei Gegenstanden, die nicht Eigentum von Privaten,
sondern von Korperschaften, namentlich des Staats waren (Stieda
1907: 305).
Whether auctions began in Grecian or Roman markets is not of
direct bearing to this discussion. Instead, as both Heichelheim
and Stieda indicate, the consideration is of the commencement of
modern auction practices upon the involvement of merchants in
trade by auction. The Romans do deserve credit for developing the
auction to its fullest extent prior to the modern era. As a
colonial institution, Mommsen finds a record from Portugal
(Mommsen 1877: 100-101); Arnobius mentions one in his native North
Africa; Flavius Josephus describes one in Syria (Blaise 1954:103).
The latter is a report out of Jewish Antiquities of an elaborate
auction on provincial taxation rights (Josephus 1943: v.7, 89-95).
Other occasions for auction in Rome include rights to farm a piece
of property (Plutarch 1906:6), estate liquidation for indebtedness
(Plautus 1949: 63), compensation for property seized by the State
(Cicero 1913: 256-9 and Long 1870: 1013); and estate liquidation
upon death (Cicero 1927: 108-109).
Mommsen records that Cato the Elder put up for auction his culled
cattle (boves vetulos) along with a variety of other lots; cattle
and slaves brought higher commissions than the usual one or two
per cent (Mommsen 1877: 92, 102). Sufficient record of Roman
auction practices remains to enable some description. The standard
reference appears to be George Long's essay in the Dictionary of
Greek and Roman Antiquities from which this account is taken. A
crier (paeco) and/or a public notice would announce the time,
place, and conditions of the auction. The crier acted as the
auctioneer as well, calling out the bids (liceri,licitari) and
entertaining the assembly. Bids were given by word of mouth or
commonly understood signals. The property would be knocked down
(addici) upon the highest bid. The bid was recorded by an
argentarius who could sue for payment if need be, and saw to the
conditions of sale. In accordance with battlefield practice, a
spear would have been put up as a symbol of the auction, the
phrase "sub haste," under the spear, recalling the sale of booty
acquired in battle (Long 1870: 172). Except for the called
announcement of the sale, the spear symbol, and the legal status
of the recorder, this could describe a current auction quite
adequately. In fact, current auctioneers frequently mention their
next auction early in the day's trading. Further, rather than
being under the spear, lots are now said to be under the hammer.
Finally, the owner of the auction house frequently acts as
recorder and has legal recourse regarding the conditions of sale,
albeit as a private citizen rather than an agent for the State.
As one might expect, a dearth of contemporary sources hampers
historical research on the period between Rome's fall and the rise
of Venice. No mention of auctions can be found between Gregorius
Magnus (pope, 590-604) (Blaise 1954: 103) and the late thirteenth
century. By this time, the words appears as auxtionarius, meaning
"retailer" or auxionatrix, meaning "huckster" (Latham 1965: 37).
Changes in trade, as well as those in the function and prevalence
of literacy, account for this pause in evidence of auctions.
Although Roman fairs had been introduced to Western Europe by 493
(Walford 1968: 7), the organization of fairs and markets did not
occur until the late Carolingian f iscal and political
improvements (Addison 1953: 26). Further, the scarcity of surplus
acted to restrict trade to essentials like iron, millstones, and
salt (Baldwin 1937: 67).
Coinage had become debased and rare, returning small trade to
barter (Lopez 1971: 18). The sale of manoral livestock was
incidental even as late as the thirteenth century, although as D.
L. Farmer points out, surplus grain was increasingly important to
the functioning of the manor (Farmer 1969: 14). By this time,
administrative laxity by the churches and impoverishment by the
tolls was causing a sharp decline in the number of fairs as they
passed into guild control (Addison 1953: 29, 61). In addition to a
minimal state of trade not being conducive to auctions, direct
competition between buyers as a means of establishing a price
seemed to violate the economic teachings of the medieval church.
Medieval business was conducted upon moral rather than contractual
bases. A just price was sought in transactions. Such prices were
arrived at by considering the conditions of the market, the cost
and risk of transportation, and production costs (O'Brien 1968:
107). Prices at fairs were usually set by an appraisal upon which
the tolls were set (Addison 1953: 69). When no just price existed,
the buyer and seller sought an equity of burden, neither
individual taking advantage of the particular need of the other
(O'Brien 1968:109ff). Once the Italian merchants and guildsmen
began to prosper again, conditions were conducive to auctions.
In 1235, Florentines issued the solidus, worth twelve denarius
(the silver penny minted about 1000). The florin quickly followed.
Indicative of increased trade, functional coinage rapidly spread
throughout Europe (Schevill 1936:291-292). As mercantile trade
advanced, the auction was reintroduced in Italy. Wilhelm Stieda
finds the first mention of modern auctions in records from a
German emporium in Venice in 1335. In the absence of records of
the goods handled, we assume that the Germans availed themselves
of the Constantine rarities for which Venitian trade was famous
(Stieda 1907:309).
The first records of bankruptcy auctions come from this century as
well. Stieda follows Jakob Grimm's work (1854-1960:entry 472),
finding an early mention of a Gant, a procedure for the seizure
and sale of goods to cover debts, in the. Badener Stadtbuch for
1384. Improvements in livestock production must have been being
made by this time since cattle figured heavily in these sales
(Stieda 1907: 305).
The word "auction" first appeared in English in William Warner's
1505 translation of Plautus' Menaechmi (Murray 1933: 559, Plautus:
1595). Earlier evidence of the institution in Britain can be
found. R. W. Patten traces a candle auction for the farming rights
on the Chedzoy church acreage back to the end of the fifteen
century (Patten 1971:60-61), Somewhat later, Samuel Kiechel
recounts an auction in Dover by a pair of enterprising Britons who
sold the wreckage of French ships sunk by the British in 1585
(Kiechel 1866:33).
Continuing in an etymological vein, note might be made of the good
Anglo-Saxon word "bid". Toiler traces the word to Aelfric's
Grammar (c. 1000) where it meant to ask, pray, or entreat (Toiler
1898 and Somner 1970: under "biddan"). By the 1400's, it could
mean offering money for goods or bargaining, as well as the
earlier meaning (Kurath 1956: under "beding", and Craigie 1937:
under "bid").
The only candidate for the same procedure as an auction under a
different name (similar to Gant for Versteigerung in German) would
be "roup". This is a Scottish word, perhaps originally from
"hrop", meaning crying, clamor, outcry as in Daer bid a wop and
hrop (there shall be ever weeping and wailing) (Toiler 1898: 563).
The entry in the Scottish National Dictionary has roup synonymous
with auction in an example from the Edinburgh Gazette of 1700
(Grant 1969:488). Wright notes that the term especially refers to
a displenishment (Wright 1905: 162), although this may indicate
more about the types of auctions undertaken than the specific
nature of the term "roup."
The Dutch East India Company held the earliest ongoing auctions in
Northern Europe related to current business practices. Probably
taking the Italian example, the Company held twice yearly sales of
their remaining stock of cloves and nutmegs (Stieda 1907:309). It
seems likely that these auctions provided the example for the
tulip auctions of the 1630's. Once commenced, auctions based on
colonial goods spread to Britain where the Hudson Bay Company also
marketed furs in a twice annual sale (Stieda 1907: 327).
George McKay finds mention of Dutch book auctions in 1584, 1593,
1596, and 1599. For the latest of these, a catalogue of the
library of Philip van Marnix was produced (McKay 1947: 236).
Alfred W. Pollard's Introduction to the British Museum's List of
Catalogues of English Book Sales gives the source of British book
auctions. They were imported from Holland upon the suggestion of
Dr. Joseph Hill in about 1653 (McKay 1947: 238). The first British
book auction for which we have a catalogue was held on October 31,
1676, when Dr. Lazarus Seaman's collection hit the block. There
have been book auctions at least annually since then (McKay 1947:
236-237).
The auction came to America through both the British and Dutch
colonists. In 1662, two book auctions were held. Stokes reports
that New Amsterdam permitted Anna Claus Croesens to sell by the
bailiff some books and property. She held a lien on the latter
(Stokes 1915-28: v. 4, p. 219). The earliest book auction in
America occurred in Boston on April 18, 1662 (Stokes 1915-28: v.
6, p. 321).
We continue indebted to Stokes for finding record of the social
side of early American auctions. He quotes a British minister and
lady describing the Dutch colonials: They have Vendues very
frequently and make their Earnings very well by them for they
treat with good Liquor Liberally, and the Customers Drink as
Liberally and Generally pay for't as well, by paying for that
which they Bidd up Briskly for, after the sack has gone
plentifully about, tho' sometimes good penny worth are got there.
(Stokes 1915-28: v. 4, p. 451). We have no record of the goods
placed for sale, although mixed lots seem probable since no
mention is made to the contrary and the sale seems to be a regular
event.
For the bibliophile, we might repeat the well known notice by
Samuel Gerrish. He offered the first known catalogue for an
American book auction (Littlefield 1900:212). The title page of
the copy at the American Antiquarian Society Library reads: A
catalog of curious and valuable books, belonging to the Late
Reverend...Mr. Ebenezer Pemberton...to be sold by auction, at the
Crown Coffee-House in Boston, the second day of July, 1717. This
auction together with that mentioned by Stokes and that of Ambrose
Vincent (1713) support McKay's assertion that book auctions came
to America through the British colony, Boston (McKay 1947: 239).
Laws indicative of the history of auctions were passed in 1794,
1813, and 1814. In 1794, a duty of ¼ of 1% was set on auctions of
"any interest, right, or estate in lands... any utensiles in
husbandry, and farming stock, ships and vessels" with ½ of 1% on
all other goods. Land sales by residents moving elsewhere and
produce sold on the land where it was raised were excepted from
duty. Congress repealed the law laying duties on stills,
pleasurable carriages, and auctions in April of 1802. Duties on
"goods, wares, and merchandise" sold at auction were reinstated at
a 1% rate in July of 1813 and raised to 2% at the end of 1814
(Peters 1845-55: v. 1, p. 397).
These later duties reflect the surge of auctioned foreign goods,
largely of British manufacture, immediately following the War of
1812. British manufacturers' agents, anticipating the end of the
war, had stockpiled goods in Halifax and Bermuda. Once the war
ended, Federal restrictions on imports from England were lifted.
In order to copy with the enormous influx of goods and to simplify
the paying of customs duties, auction houses were established in
Eastern seaports (Jones 1968:33).
In an excellent description of the middlemen in American trade in
the first half of the nineteenth century, Fred M. Jones describes
the reaction of importers and jobbers to this interruption in
their chain of trade (Jones 1968: 34-35). These businessmen, with
the support of Niles' National Register (1811-1849),
unsuccessfully petitioned Congress for tenfold increases of duties
and the abolition of customs credits. Their pamphlet,
The Reasons Why the Present System
of Auctions Ought to be Abolished (1828), outlines their
case. As well as tending toward monopoly, concentrating trade,
enhancing prices, and harming both American manufacturers and
importers, auctions were said to produce all the pernicious effect
of gambling (Jones 1968:36). The auctioneers responded with
An Examination of Reasons the
Present System of Auctions Ought to Be Abolished (1828).
Ray Westerfield provides factors in the decline of auctions in the
1830's. He states that steam navigation opened the interior ports,
thus allowing meetings of commission house representatives and
jobbers (Westerfield 1920:208). This corresponds with Jones'
finding that importers and jobbers were forced off the Eastern
Seaboard to solicit the business of country merchants who might
otherwise have attended import auctions (Jones 1968:39). Further,
merchants could get eight to ten months' credit in private sales,
as opposed to six months from auction sales (Jones 1968:40). This
meant that shopkeepers could buy during the midwinter business
lull, recover interest costs by passing them on to farmers buying
on credit, and have the notes come due after being paid out of
harvest profits. The alternative would have been a lengthy
purchasing trip to the coast just as the agricultural year was
beginning.
Finally, the development of American manufacturing, especially
textiles and dry goods, acted to increase the relative cost of
British imports (Jones 1968:39, and Westerfield 1920:108). In
fact, the share of American products increased at the New York
auctions from 7 to 25% between 1820 and 1830 (Jones 1968:33) (Note
4). Broadsides attest to the auction as a popular institution
throughout the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. A glance
through the catalogues of prominent library collections indicates
the range of locations and goods handled.
From the William L. Clements Library at the University of
Michigan, we find descriptions of broadsides from New York State
announcing a sale of a great variety of articles (1835) and an
estate sale of wood and timber (1842). Similarly, the Glenbow
Historical Library in Alberta describes broadsides for a variety
of Alberta purebred livestock auctions at the turn of the century.
The Bancroft Library has been particularly thorough in cataloging
California auction notices and catalogues. These include the
jewelry of Lola Montez (1856), houselots and real estate (1850,
1853, 1860), cargo (1849), and elegant and rustic furnishings
(1873). These California sales indicate the capacity of the
auction method to establish the worth of items in the volatile
economy of the gold rush. one anticipates that the earlier prices
were considerably higher than the later ones.
Precursors of present day cattle auctions appear in the middle of
the nineteenth century. The first public livestock auction in
America occurred in Ohio in 1836. This sale by the Ohio Company
was also the first sale of purebred cattle in America. Monthly
sales of commercial livestock, as well, were begun in Ohio by the
Madison County Importing Company. In Kentucky in the 1850's,
"court day" sales, resembling European "tax day" sales, were held
on the first Monday of each month (Engelman and Pence 1958:3-4,
and Howe 1896: v. 2, p. 167) (Note 5).
The normal purpose for auctions during the nineteenth century,
however, was more likely to be for the disposal of remainders and
unclaimed items. Here, an item in the Tucson Daily Record for May
6, 1880, reveals that the local auctioneer was well enough known
to be identifiable by initials: Auctioneer OH held a sale
yesterday and disposed of several horses, harness, etc., all of
which brought good prices. ("Auctioneer" 1880:3). Richthofen
records a practice hearkening back to medieval solutions for found
items. Local stock associations 39 received the proceeds of
auctioned unattached range calves and unbranded cattle during the
era of cowboy roundups (Richthofen 1885:36).
Still, the Ohio and Kentucky precedents certainly establish the
connection between agricultural production and auctions. Isolated
livestock auctions were also established after the turn of the
century. These includes auctions in Iowa (1904), Ohio (1911,
established by Mennonites), Nebraska (1912), California (1917)
(Note 6), and Minnesota (1919) (Engelman and Pence 1958:3-5).
Figures taken from articles by Engelman and Pence (1958:5) and by
Abel and Broadbent (1952:Appendix A) readily illustrate that
widespread acceptance of decentralized marketing of livestock
using the auction method began in the 1930's.
Nationally, the number of livestock auction markets increased from
about 200 to about 2,000 during this decade (Figure 1). In the
Western region, two phases of growth are recorded. The first,
between 1935 and 1940, resulted in an increase from fifty-six to
179 markets. The second, immediately upon the end of World War II,
shows an increase of 179 markets in a three year period (Figure
2). Factors facilitating decentralized marketing, referring to
Abel and Broadbent (1952:48) and Engelman and Pence (1958:5-6)
again, include: 1 ) improved and extended hard surfaced roads and
thereby increased trucking potential just as motor carriers were
being improved; 2) growing numbers of small packers and improved
refrigeration both at the plants and en route; 3) the development
of uniform grade and weight classifications (see factors 4 and 8
below); 4) improved collection and dissemination of market news
for both buyers and sellers by the federal government; 5)
increased transportation and marketing expenses relative to
declining livestock prices in 1930-1933; 6) increased local market
for immature and unfinished stock due to drought-caused abnormal
feed distribution in the West; 7) increasing numbers of odd lots
ready for market, especially as fed livestock entered into farm
programs; 8) wartime regulations, especially tire and gasoline
rationing; 9) local pressure to improve and diversify community
markets and services; 10) desire by producers to see livestock
sold rather than shipped to private treaty system terminal
markets.
Most generally, dwellers in rural neighborhoods availed themselves
of technological developments to bring together competing
producers and buyers of livestock. The community was identified as
the appropriate locus of working social gatherings. So considered,
livestockmen asserted the integral relationship between work and
social group. Further, this development implies that marketing is
an aspect of production. This change from centralized terminal
markets located at some distance from the range to smaller auction
houses nearer the livestockmen recalls a process first described
by Johann Heinrich von Thünen (Thünen 1966: for an abbreviated
description of his theory, see Peet 1970-71). He proposed a
continuum of the intensity of agriculture varying upon the
distance to a sizable market. The nearer to an urban center, the
more expensive the land, the more intensive the agriculture, the
more productive and smaller the holdings. Feed lots, terminal
markets, and truck farms are more likely found around large
population centers. Open range grazing, the least intensive form
of production, would be found furthest from these urban centers.
The ratio of transportation and production costs, which are
important to von Thünens thesis, did change dramatically in the
1930's and 1940's.
The development of small, more intensive holdings and thereby the
need for a market which could handle smaller lots could readily
explain the introduction of livestock auction markets. More
importantly, von Thünen's theories would explain the persistence
of private treaty marketing in the terminal exchanges in the
larger cities, Von ThLinen's demographic theories will play a role
in a subsequent geographical discussion as well.
Summary
Auctions developed as a means whereby the State could equitably
distribute property obtained as the spoils of war, the results of
taxation, or legal seizures for debt or legal misconduct. Where
relatively free markets exist, merchants may adopt the practice in
order to efficiently establish prices, particularly for trade in
large numbers of transactions. The conditions prevalent during
periods when auctions are present and absent can be readily
contrasted. During times of controlled commodity prices, as in the
marketless economies before the Agora and the medieval markets
governed by a just price, auctions are incidental trade methods.
By contrast, during periods of relatively free market prices, as
in the Roman Empire and since the Renaissance Italian city states,
auctions flourish. Extreme instances of the auction in free price
markets occur during trade in popular rarities (exotic spices,
books and coins, art) or prize specimens (tulips, registered
livestock or pets). Again, the heterogeneity of trade goods
prevalent during periods of foreign or long distance trade
encourage auctions while the homogeneity of commodities from local
trade suppress auctions. The modest medieval markets and the
restricted trade during the War of 1812 contrast with Roman,
Dutch, and English colonial trade and the contemporary rural
American livestock production destined for urban dweller. (A
sophisticated economic history is called for to establish the
nature of the relationship discerned in this informal summary
between heterogeneous trade goods, free market prices, and
auctions).
The livestock auctions under study here, however, are something of
a special case. They do occur during a period of relatively free
market prices and as part of a long distance trade mechanism. In
colonial trade relationships, primary and manufactured products
were auctioned near the site of consumption. For example, the
Hudson Bay Company sold its furs at auction in London. Woolens
woven in Liverpool in the 1810's were auctioned in New York City.
In livestock marketing, however, price setting competition occurs
first at the site of production. This is neither an accident of
circumstance nor a necessary condition since livestock had been
marketed previously through centralized commission sales at some
distance from the farms and ranches. Instead, livestockmen
consciously chose a marketing technique which allowed them greater
community participation, electing an opportunity for Gemeinschaft
within Gesellschaft.